Print
Version
Limits to Large-Scale Reconstruction IN HONDURAS: Land Development for
LOW-INCOME HOUSING in
Inadequately Functioning Land Markets
Glenn Pearce-Oroz
Introduction
The constantly evolving and dynamic use of land by human
activity has been an object of study for more than a century. From the
earliest observers of how society allocates land uses differently (J.H.
von Thunen, George Perkins Marsh) to more recent attempts to understand
the principles driving land use change (William Alonso, Manuel Castells,
and Allen Scott) the performance of land markets continues to be
influenced by many variables with varying degrees of impact. Increasing
our understanding of land market behavior requires the consideration of
each moving part separately, all moving parts collectively, and the
context within which they must operate. Particularly in developing
countries, because of the discord that exists between legal provisions
and practice, the institutional context within which the land market
must operate is an overarching variable that will influence other
aspects of land market functionality. Accordingly, as would be
advocated by structuralist-institutionalist theorists, an accurate
analysis of the land market in development countries must first and
foremost take stock of institutional realities.
The most basic manifestation of a poorly performing formal
land market is one where the supply of land does not satisfy the
demand. Over time, this type of land market failure becomes a driving
force in shaping the city because it forces economic actors to adopt
strategies outside the formal market for obtaining and using land. In
many developing countries these alternative strategies evolve into full
blown parallel land markets which sometimes threaten to overshadow
formal mechanisms. The prolonged systematic development of these
settlements in the context of an unregulated land market leads to
inefficient land-use patterns where the construction of infrastructure
and the delivery of services become costly and where settlement patterns
are more markedly segregated by economic power.
In the context of long-term inefficient, high-risk settlement
patterns, natural phenomena (hurricanes, storms, floods, land slides,
earthquakes, etc.) can quickly multiply their disastrous consequences.
The pattern of destruction is greatly increased when a storm strikes
settlements in environmentally high-risk areas such as natural drainage
channels, unstable hillsides, and floodplains. To a certain degree,
reconstruction after large-scale destruction offers a unique opportunity
for land market corrections. Urban dwellers in high risk zones are
temporarily displaced (or longer) from these areas, an instant high
demand for homes and buildings materializes, special financing for
infrastructure may become available, and new urbanization patterns can
be influenced. There are also formidable obstacles with which to
contend as a result of these phenomena including human suffering,
delivery of basic services, control against public health epidemics, and
the increased urgency for quickly resettling displaced families. As the
following analysis demonstrates, immediate opportunities for land market
corrections and impact are short-lived and limited by the same
institutional and structural constraints of the land market that existed
before the emergency; the same constraints that contributed to market
inefficiencies in the first place.
By focusing on three of the larger human settlements built
during the reconstruction period following Hurricane Mitch (October,
1998), an opportunity exists to understand how these urban land markets
respond to large-scale public sector interventions and how this type of
land development has shaped urbanization patterns, if at all, six years
later. Three variables that have driven change in these land markets
will be addressed: lack of enforcement of planning regulations; poorly
functioning non-regulatory components of land markets; and agent-based
choices and strategies. Corrective measures, policy incentives, and the
appropriate role of local governments will also be discussed.
The consequences of unenforced
regulations and poorly functioning land markets
In their most rudimentary expression, land markets are shaped
by the amount of land supplied by owners and the amount of land demanded
by users. Therefore the mechanisms and systems that facilitate these
transactions are fundamental for the functioning of the land market. If
legally sanctioned mechanisms operate well for all types of actors that
wish to participate in the land market, then the majority of
transactions between supplier and demander will be transacted in the
formal market. If these factors are weak or not easily accessible to
all economic agents, whether on the supply or the demand-side, the
functioning of the formal land market can become obstructed at best or
obsolete at worst. The extent to which mechanisms outside the formal
market become a viable alternative will depend on the success, or lack
thereof, of potential supply and potential demand resolving their
needs. Ultimately, market forces will adapt to both the regulatory as
well as the non-regulatory environment. In developing countries such as
Honduras, regulatory measures may be legislated to function in a certain
manner, such as the urban boundary or infrastructure requirements for
residential areas, but in practice may prove to have unintended impacts.
Local governments have mechanisms available with wide-ranging
effectiveness to influence the behavior of land markets. Land use
regulations, zoning ordinances, subdivision standards, concurrent
infrastructure requirements, land taxation schemes, and the imposition
of urban growth boundaries are all tools that affect the supply of land
with varying degrees of success. The effectiveness of these regulations
is predicated largely on the administrative and coercive capacity of the
local government to manage and enforce them. When land market analysts
cite the relevance of land use regulations for shaping the behavior of
the land market, they are implicitly assuming that local governments are
effectively enforcing existing regulations. In developing countries
with weak institutions, this is a false assumption. Most of these
regulations, if they exist at all, go unenforced and thereby provide no
real limiting impact to the functioning of the formal land market.
Local government ineffectiveness is a driving factor that leads to a
de facto under-regulated land market where even the most basic
regulatory measures, such as prohibiting development in environmentally
high risk zones or limiting urban growth to an established urban
boundary,[1]
remain unenforced. Within this context, the acquisition and development
of land tends to be mostly affected by non-regulatory market forces. In
Honduras, as in other countries in the developing world with a closed or
captured economy, these non-regulatory market forces are accessible by a
relatively limited number of actors who manipulate public and private
institutions for their own benefit (Hellman et al 2000). In this
respect, formal markets that resolve the transactions of a limited
number of privileged economic actors are no longer viable systems for
the public-at-large to efficiently fulfill its needs for land.
The limitations in effective governance at the local level in
Honduras are mirrored by the poorly functioning non-regulatory
components that underlie land market dynamics: financing mechanisms, the
property rights regime, and the provision of infrastructure.
In the case of Honduras, both supply and demand are faced
with limited financial mechanisms and products to finance their
activities in the land market. When financing mechanisms are not
sufficiently diversified and competitive, or are limited by a fragile
financial system, financing becomes scarce and prohibitively expensive
for most developers (supply) and buyers (demand) of new land. In part,
the fragile state of the Honduran financial system and vulnerability of
its relatively small banking sector[2]
is due to the way in which the country has handled agricultural credit
and losses (IMF 2003). The government bail-out of debtors has
negatively impacted the financial system by encouraging moral hazard and
damaging market discipline. The consequences for land market
transactions are further complicated by banks’ reluctance to provide
mortgage-backed credit where property rights are uncertain and when
court proceedings for foreclosure are lengthy. These factors and a
higher non-performing loan to total loan ratio in Honduras as compared
to other Central American countries has made the banking sector more
conservative in its loan-making.
Most consumers of land and housing, especially the largest
sector of the population,[3]
do not qualify for mechanisms offered by the formal banking sector. For
this consumer cohort, mechanisms outside the banking sector are also
limited. One promising outlet for low-income families is the
Fundación para el Desarrollo de la Vivienda Social y Rural (FUNDEVI),
created in 2002 to provide financing to those households with monthly
incomes of between two and six baskets of basic goods. During 2003 and
2004, FUNDEVI authorized a total of 1,499 credits and subsidies in
Tegucigalpa, Choluteca, and El Progreso (FUNDEVI 2005), still well below
the existing demand and representing only a fraction of the post-Mitch
housing boom.
Consumers are also confronted by a deficient property rights
regime that encumbers the legal transfer of land and the commodification
of property. In Honduras, an estimated US$8 billion of real estate
property in urban areas has been identified as dead or inactive capital
(ILD 2001), that is, capital which is not captured by the formal market
and cannot be utilized as a source for generating additional wealth or
economic activity. Inaccurate land registry systems, complicated
registry practices that produce long delays, and a weak judicial system
that does not adequately enforce property rights and resolve disputes in
ownership all contribute to the inefficiency and weakness of the formal
land market. The nominal-based registries, in place from 1906 through
2004, provided titles linked primarily to the owner and described by
imprecise measurements,[4]
rather than linking title more explicitly to the physical property as
described by objective measurements. In this type of system, the
purchase and sale, subdivision, or assembly of land becomes difficult to
transact without disputes. This was the system under which the
explosive urbanization of the 1970’s and 1980’s took place in Honduras.
Infrastructure provision is also an important input to ensure
that raw land is available for appropriate residential, commercial,
industrial, or public uses. The intensive land use that accompanies
urban areas makes the provision of infrastructure all the more critical
for cities experiencing growth. The ability to provide serviced land at
a reasonable cost and rapidly enough to accommodate urban growth is
necessary in order for the supply of land to satisfy the potential
demand. The two important obstacles that impede the efficient
development of public networks of water and sanitation in Honduras,
financing and operation and management, are closely linked. If there
are few or no viable financing mechanisms available, it becomes
difficult to finance the repair and rehabilitation of existing systems
or construct new ones. Similarly, when the internal management systems
of the service provider are not operationally and financially
sustainable, the provision of existing services, not to mention the
needs of an expanding urban population, is further complicated.
Because the components that make up the land market function
poorly or include structural barriers that limit access to the formal
market, individuals who utilize these scarce mechanisms are afforded
highly privileged positions within the economic system. They become
economic elites not because of their competitiveness but because of
their access and ability to maneuver within the captured formal market.
The privileged access to limited information, as well as financial and
legal systems, creates a high level of inequity in the patterns of land
occupation and human settlements within the larger city.
Throughout Latin America this type of inequity is manifested
in well-known urbanization trends characterized by the proliferation of
irregular land development. Without access to the formal land markets
and in the absence of enforced regulations, low and even some
middle-income groups throughout the region have opted for settlement
strategies outside the formal land market. Because of the inability of
land markets to provide sufficient supply for the ever increasing demand
for urban land, many cities now have significant portions of their
inhabitants living in irregular settlements: an estimated 59% of the
urban population in Bogotá, 50% in Caracas, 50% in Quito, 40% in Mexico
City, and 50% in Tegucigalpa (Clichevsky 2000, PADCO 1998). These
irregular settlements can be characterized by their origins: land
invasions, illegal subdivisions and purchases, and incremental expansion
of existing settlements (Angel 2002). Whereas invasions were
characteristic of early generation solutions to the land crisis (1960’s
and 70’s), this type of occupation of space is now rare. In Honduras,
for example, the evidence suggests that more and more, irregular land
development and occupation is being conducted through some type of
market transactions albeit outside the formerly established mechanisms.
As a result
of the existing financial, property rights, and infrastructure
constraints, only a small sector of the population can benefit from the
formal market. Land development occurs in the formal sector, but only
in a limited form by few actors with large capital reserves or
privileged access to land. Consequently, a great deal of potential
demand for land remains unresolved in the formal sector and is directed
to informal market mechanisms. In Tegucigalpa the formal land market
produced 24 residential subdivisions (for all income groups) between
2000 and 2004 for an approximate total of 4,600 housing solutions (METROPLAN
2005). However, during this time period the city increased by an
estimated 18,457 households (INE 2001). The remaining 13,857 households
not covered by the 24 residential subdivisions produced by the formal
land market were forced to resolve their needs through irregular
mechanisms or by overcrowding existing units, both of which tend to lead
to substandard living conditions.
An important and direct consequence of the poorly functioning
land markets has been the equally inadequate performance of the housing
sector. In Honduras, housing deficits have historically remained high
while the production of housing units has been consistently low. An
estimated average of 3,500 new housing units were built annually on a
national level by the formal market (both public and private housing
starts for all income groups) in the 1980’s, and 5,100 new housing units
produced annually by the formal market from 1994-1996 (Pisani 1997).
This is compared to the 46,700 units per year that need to be built or
renovated to satisfy existing deficits. Unquestionably more housing has
been produced during this time period, just not within the formal
sector.
Reconstruction for displaced families
For many years before Hurricane Mitch, poor practices of land
management in the country’s largest cities took place. During the
period of low urbanization rates, the inefficient land use patterns
produced in the absence of regulation and enabled by poorly functioning
land markets were manageable. As the rates of urbanization picked up in
Honduras (1970-1990), the consequences of previously deficient land
markets became compounded. In the unregulated land market, land supply
was not providing enough for the land being demanded, the property
rights regime could not address the influx of transactions, and the lack
of infrastructure financing caused deficits in basic services. Under
this paradigm, those who were able to overcome these constraints,
possess sufficient financing, or access to scarce information, were able
to participate in the formal market. The majority of the population
that did not have easy access to financing or for whom land was not
available were forced to adopt alternative strategies.
In each of the three cities included in this analysis,
informal settlements began to spread in areas not optimal for the
provision of services or in environmental risk zones. Hurricane Mitch,
a 100-year storm, did significant damage to these areas. Destruction
would have been great because of the magnitude of this storm, but was
all the greater because of settlement patterns that took place in a
poorly functioning land market with unenforced regulations.
Nationwide,
approximately 33,000 homes were destroyed and 50,000 were damaged by the
hurricane. In the three-year reconstruction period that followed
(1999-2001), an estimated 27,000 homes were rebuilt within the
constraints of the formal land and housing markets (UPPV, 2001),
representing the largest boom in land and housing development for
low-income families in the country’s history.
The seemingly endless amount of funds provided by donor
countries and other relief organizations helped to level the playing
field (at least temporarily) in terms of access to land and housing
markets by low-income families, but not in any permanent or structural
way. As a result of the injection of economic and political resources,
existing barriers were overcome and access to the formal land market was
achieved on behalf of the poor. Financial viability was no longer a
constraining factor, nor was the absence of infrastructure financing
since the reconstruction efforts included funds for the development of
raw land. The barriers inherent in land ownership continued to
represent a constraint but were ultimately resolved by political and
economic influence, the type not available to the common low-income
dweller under normal circumstances. Beneficiaries were offered an
unprecedented opportunity to receive legal title to newly constructed
homes connected to basic services in environmentally risk-free zones.
Despite the substantial gains in land development and housing
production, this type of donor-led approach is not an efficient or
sustainable way to build low-income housing because of high per-unit
costs and the size of subsidies that far out-strips the national
capacity. Six years after the hurricane, housing and land markets
continue to function poorly even though urbanization trends were
appreciably influenced in some localized cases.
Three of the cities hardest hit by the effects of the
hurricane were Tegucigalpa, Choluteca, and El Progreso.
Tegucigalpa
In Tegucigalpa (pop. 980,000) (INE 2001a), the Honduran
capital located in mountainous terrain, torrential rains caused
large-scale destruction, land-slides, and flooding. The long-standing
urban growth of Tegucigalpa, with limited enforcement of zoning
regulations, had led to an inefficient settlement pattern prior to the
hurricane that expanded along hillsides and in high-risk zones. This
type of uncontrolled growth made the delivery of basic services as well
as the construction of roads and drainage systems very costly. In the
absence of sufficient financing programs, most of this infrastructure
has not been adequately addressed by the public authorities and has been
left to the initiative of the dwellers. Due to the ineffectiveness of
the formal land market, most urban dwellers have opted to resolve their
residential needs through the informal market. By 1998, an estimated
225 of the 340 neighborhoods in the city were occupied by informal or
irregular settlements often times located in high risk areas (PADCO
1998).
Urbanization in Tegucigalpa was highest in the 1970s and
1980s, rising at an estimated 7% annually (INE 1974, 1988, 2001a).
Figure 1 provides a comparison of the three cities analyzed in this
study. Tegucigalpa is the most urbanized municipal district in a
country that is still undergoing important demographic shifts from rural
to urban areas.[5]
Nationally, the Honduran population is roughly evenly divided between
Figure 1. Urban Growth
Rates (1975-2015)

Source: INE 1974, 1988,
2001a, 2001b
urban and rural
dwellers, contrasting sharply with high levels of urbanization across
Latin America. The growth of the urban population in Tegucigalpa is
expected to continue to grow albeit at a reduced rate, with medium-sized
cities such as Choluteca and El Progreso experiencing greater rates of
urban growth over the coming decade.
An
estimated 2,500 families from 12 neighborhoods were permanently
displaced in Tegucigalpa as a result of Hurricane Mitch without any
other housing option available (IOM 1999). These families were first
temporarily housed in macro-shelters in two locations in the city, both
with similar access (or better) to jobs and markets than they had in
their original neighborhoods. The consolidation of these families in
these macro-shelters allowed for NGO’s and other housing developers to
easily identify potential demand for their projects.
Most of the
funds for housing reconstruction pledged by donor governments were
implemented through (mostly international) NGO’s. Almost immediately it
became evident that the largest obstacle to this reconstruction effort
was the availability of land on which to develop 2,500 housing units.
Despite the generous urban boundary established in 1979, a large
percentage of which is still raw land, large tracts were scarce. Many
potential parcels had disputed tenure, were not in risk free zones, or
were not large enough to generate the necessary economies of scale
required by the number of displaced families and the funds available.
In addition, the Central District’s municipality, Tegucigalpa’s local
government, lacked the ability or the political will to maneuver within
the existing constraints of the land market and provide coordination
assistance to the NGO’s.[6]
Confronted with limited options within the urban boundary, NGO land
developers began to widen their search and located within the Amarateca
Valley land with free and clear title, in environmentally safe areas,
and in the dimension needed. Eventually six housing projects were built
in this valley extending between 12 and 26 kilometers from the city’s
northern outskirts but within the Central District’s municipal limits. This valley, with two rural villages and a population of
3,200 inhabitants prior to Mitch reconstruction, had been designated as
an area for industrial expansion in 1976, but still remained largely
unpopulated and undeveloped at the time the new settlements were built.
The resettlement of a large urban population to this area far from the
urban core has proven economically challenging for many dwellers, most
of whom depended on the urban economy for jobs and commerce. Whereas in
their previous locations, both before the hurricane and during the time
they occupied the macro-shelters, displaced families maintained a
reliable connection to prospective places of employment, there are now
additional hurdles to an already difficult job market. For example, a
worker commuting six days a week from the new towns to Tegucigalpa would
spend US$5.16[7]
(10-16 percent) of a median weekly household income estimated between
US$33 and 50 (IOM 2001). The employed population of the new towns must
therefore either absorb the transportation costs (time and money) to
remain active participants in the Tegucigalpa economy or retool to
become more competitive in the local job market.
By 2004, approximately 3,700 housing units and accompanying
social infrastructure such as primary schools and community centers had
been built in the Amarateca Valley, representing a resettled population
of approximately 18,500 inhabitants. Although systematic surveys are
lacking, anecdotal evidence suggests that a number of the dwellers of
these new towns of Tegucigalpa have sold their new homes and returned to
the city, or have established dual households, one in Tegucigalpa and
the other in Amarateca.
Map 1. Tegucigalpa Urban Boundary and Amarateca Valley
  
The absence of police
and public safety as well as sustainable services further differentiates
the new settlements from the rest of the urban population. One of the
most negative developments has been the increase of crime and gang
activity in some of the reconstruction settlements creating a serious
obstacle to community development and further segregation of these
citizens from the rest of the city. In similar terms, the lack of
sustainable basic services is another factor which segregates these
formal urban dwellers from other inhabitants of the city’s formal
sectors. Independent water and sanitation systems have been built to
service these new settlements that are geographically outside the scope
of the national water authority that provides services to the rest of
the city. Given this institutional limbo, the long-term operation and
maintenance of the newly constructed water and sanitation systems
remains unclear.
Choluteca
The effects of the hurricane also ravaged the southern city
of Choluteca located along the Choluteca River in the lower part of the
watershed. This medium-sized city with 76,000 inhabitants (INE 2001a)
was affected not only by the rains that fell, but also by the
accumulated sediment and materials that drained down from Tegucigalpa
and other parts in the upper watershed. The flooding that took place
along the banks of the Choluteca River destroyed an estimated 25
neighborhoods and displaced approximately 3,000 families (CEDAC 1999a).
Although many of these original homes had running water and electricity,
most families did not have free and clear title to their land.
The settlement pattern in Choluteca, currently the sixth
largest city in Honduras, was also shaped by a poorly functioning land
market and unenforced regulations. However, the extent of widespread
disputed land rights in and around Tegucigalpa did not materialize in
this medium-sized city and the land demanded by a growing urban
population, most pronounced in the 1970’s and 1980’s, in real terms did
not exert the same type of strain on the formal land market as in
Tegucigalpa (see Figures 2 & 3). While the urban area experienced high
growth rates over the past 30 years, this represented an estimated
demand of 30.9 hectares for residential use in any given year,[8]
compared to ten times as much (314.0 hectares demanded annually) in
Tegucigalpa. In addition, the existing urban limit in Choluteca
provides ample room for incremental growth for a municipal district
whose urban/rural population (64% urban and 36% rural) follows closely
the national trends. The type of development pattern that ensued
produced intensive residential land-use along the banks of the river and
within the floodplain.
Figure 2: Estimated demand for urban residential land
(1974-1988)

Source: Estimates based on census data (INE 1974, 1988), estimated land
use requirements (Urban Institute 2004), and household income
distribution (UNDP 2003)
Figure 3: Estimated
demand for urban residential land (1989-2001)

Source: Estimates based on census data (INE 1988, 2001a), estimated
land use requirements (Urban Institute 2004), and household income
distribution (UNDP 2003)
Unlike the experience in the country’s capital, the municipal
government in Choluteca assumed a direct role in coordinating the
emergency relief and housing reconstruction. Because it was one of the
hardest hit areas nation-wide, a great deal of relief and aid was
directed to Choluteca resulting in five major housing developments that
benefited a total of 2,928 families. Similar to the case of
Tegucigalpa, the amount of reconstruction resources available for land
and housing development presented an opportunity without precedent for
the displaced low-income population. For the first time well-financed,
viable demand for low-income housing entered into the formal land
market. The largest of the projects to benefit displaced families was
Limón de la Cerca (or Ciudad Nueva Juan Benito Guevara)
consisting of 2,400 individual plots just outside the urban boundary. The municipality assumed an active role in contributing to
the solution of homes by coordinating the purchase of this parcel from a
local bank and serving as the co-signer of loans to beneficiary
families. New infrastructure had to be provided, but unlike the case of Amarateca, the three-kilometer distance between the city and the newly
constructed settlement made it feasible to connect the residential
infrastructure to the existing urban network. In particular, trunk
lines for the sewerage system were built to connect Ciudad Nueva’s
internal network to the city’s existing wastewater collection and
treatment system.
The families who now
live in Ciudad Nueva benefited from housing units with access to basic
services and the potential to obtain free and clear title to their
property, a situation that was not readily available in their original
neighborhoods. Because the settlement is located along a major roadway
leading to many of the largest agro-businesses in the area,
accessibility to jobs was also enhanced by this location. One of the
potential factors, however, that may encourage an out-migration from the
project is public safety. Similar to Amarateca, Limón de la Cerca has
become a magnet for increased delinquency and gang activity.
El Progreso
El Progreso (pop. 94,797) (INE 2001a), one of the most
affected cities in the northern part of the country, first began to
experience significant growth in the early part of the 20th
Century as a result of international investments that financed the
large-scale banana production and exporting industry. Over the past 25
years, agro-exports have been complemented by an increase in maquilas,
or assembly-for-export factories, that have taken root along the
corridor between Puerto Cortés, Central America’s largest port, and
Villanueva.
As the fifth largest city in the country, El Progreso’s
urbanization rate has jumped drastically in recent decades. Prior to
1988, only 55% of the municipality was urban, but by 2005, an estimated
81% of the population lived in the urban area (INE 2001b). This type of
growth, more accelerated than that experienced by Choluteca, combined
with the constraints of a poorly functioning land market and unenforced
regulations resulted in the occupation of public and private land along
the river. Despite having received certain services, the families that
inhabited this stretch were not connected to the public water or
sanitation systems, nor did they have legal title to their land. As in
Choluteca, flooding caused by the massive rains accounted for the
displacement of approximately 1,000 families in neighborhoods that had
expanded along the Ulua River and its tributaries (CEDAC 1999b).
The reconstruction of homes in both urban and rural areas of
El Progreso received substantial investment from many donor and relief
organizations. Similar to Choluteca, the municipality of El Progreso
played an instrumental role in identifying, assembling, and purchasing
tracts of land for reconstruction projects to take place. The largest
of these projects was Colonia San Jorge, a 500-home development located
adjacent to an urbanized part of the city’s southern periphery well
within the established urban limits and with close proximity to the main
highway. In this regard, the development of this area is
very similar to what may have naturally occurred without the emergency
of the hurricane. Infrastructure systems in Colonia San Jorge were
built, remain independent and are operated by a local water board
providing a good example of decentralized management to community
entities. This arrangement also reflects the distrust between
inhabitants and service providers that resulted in the community’s
stated preference for managing its own basic services.
This 500-home project was developed by a single NGO, the
Comité de Reconstrucción de la Iglesia Católica (CRIC), which was
recognized for having implemented one of the better practices during
hurricane reconstruction for building an integrated subdivision. The
land use plan of the subdivision was innovative and addressed many
existing social and community priorities, such as a home for the
elderly, ample open space, and additional community infrastructure. In
addition, the inter-institutional coordination between the NGO, the
municipality, and the beneficiary community was considered exemplary (CEDAC
2002). Because of its participatory approach, the community has
consolidated with more success than other settlements as evidenced by
the improvements made to most of the homes. The location of the
development and easy access to urban markets by its residents is another
factor that contributes to the long-term sustainability of this
neighborhood.
Understanding land
market responses to large-scale public sector intervention
In all
three examples, the reconstruction settlements contributed to satisfying
unmet demand for land by families without access to the formal land and
housing markets. Beyond satisfying needs for housing solutions, these
projects have the potential to make a larger, more strategic impact on
the evolution of each city, its economic development, and
competitiveness.
The varied land market responses to the large-scale public
intervention in each of the three cities provide some insight for
understanding what factors may or may not promote change in land markets
of developing countries. In comparing land market behavior during and
after the reconstruction efforts, three phenomena distinguish the cases
of Choluteca and El Progreso with that of Tegucigalpa: (1) the role of
the municipal government, (2) the ability to assemble large tracts of
land within or close to the urban boundary, and (3) the development of
infrastructure.
As
discussed above, the local governments in both Choluteca and El Progreso
assumed pivotal roles in responding to the emergencies that arose after
the hurricane, both in terms of organizing clean-up efforts and serving
as catalysts for reconstruction activities. This type of leadership not
only illustrates the potential of local governments in medium-sized
cities, but also demonstrates that municipalities can be protagonists in
the land market and land development process. In contrast, no
significant coordination effort was provided by the Central District’s
municipal government. The result, as discussed earlier, was a combined
effort by a multitude of NGO’s and relief organizations to identify
tracts of land suitable for the resettlement of displaced families.
Since the end of reconstruction, both of these medium-sized
municipalities have reduced their participation in the land market and
have focused on other priorities. Although they stay engaged in the
consolidation process of the resettlement projects,[9]
development of new housing is no longer considered pressing. The
Central District has yet to define its role regarding the new housing
settlements in Amarateca.
The ability
to assemble large tracts within or near the urban boundary, the second
element distinguishing these cases, is the result of the particular
dynamics in each of the three land markets. In the cases of Choluteca
and El Progreso, undisputed property was available at a reasonable
distance from the city. In both these cases, the cities’ urbanization
trends have been enhanced by the settlement of low-income populations in
safe conditions and with reasonable access to labor and urban markets.
Continued urban growth in Choluteca and El Progreso has been influenced
by these projects and continued land development has occurred in and
around both reconstruction settlements.
In Tegucigalpa, however, a long-standing problem stemming
from invasions during the 1970s and 1980s of private, communal and
public lands increased property insecurity and made land with free and
clear title even more scarce. Development that takes place in this
context assumes these risks and includes them in their final costs,
effectively pricing out a large sector of the population. As a result
of this market imperfection, the large tracts of land needed in the
capital for the reconstruction of homes were not easily located within
the urban boundary. The human settlement expansion north of the city in Amarateca has proven to be contrary to prevailing market forces which
are currently channeling urban growth towards the southern part of the
city.
The third
phenomenon that promotes change and differentiates these cases is the
development of residential infrastructure (especially water and
sanitation). This variable illustrates the importance of the
availability of serviced land and its effect on the land market. In
terms of basic services, the central water and sanitation authority (Servicio
Autónomo Nacional de Agua y Alcantarillado, SANAA) manages service
delivery in both Tegucigalpa and El Progreso.[10]
Of these three cities, only Choluteca has a local service provider.
Regardless of this difference, each of the systems is historically
ill-equipped to generate their own infrastructure investment. As a
consequence, investment plans and infrastructure development in
anticipation of demand for land is virtually nonexistent and highly
dependent on donor funds. In the case of the SANAA system in El
Progreso, for example, all large infrastructure investments over the
past five years have been made with donor funds, while the Tegucigalpa
SANAA water system damaged as a result of Hurricane Mitch was
rehabilitated with funds from official bilateral cooperation.
Similarly, Choluteca’s local service provider has received significant
investment over the past years via donor funding.
Consistent with this pattern, donor funds were again the
principal source of investment for reconstruction settlements’
infrastructure needs. In each of these three cases and as a consequence
of large amounts of funding, land availability, not infrastructure
costs, was the determining factor for subdivision development. For El
Progreso’s Colonia San Jorge, the most strategic land development of all
three in terms of incremental urban growth, a decision was made by the
CRIC to pursue an independent water delivery and wastewater collection
system. As part of the community approach advocated by the NGO, the
residential infrastructure would be managed by a local water board made
up of community members. Nevertheless, the expansion of the city to the
south has since given rise to additional developments in and around
Colonia San Jorge. The case of Choluteca’s Ciudad Nueva may be the most
strategic investment of the three for promoting medium-term growth. Its
proximity to the urban area allows it to be connected to the city’s
existing sanitation system via sewer trunk lines. Ciudad Nueva now
serves as one pole of a land development corridor and provides a strong
incentive for the development of tracts of land between the city and
Limón de la Cerca. As demonstrated by increased investment and new
subdivisions in this land development corridor, the land market is
already reacting to this important investment.
The least strategic and most isolated infrastructure
investment of all three cases is that of the new towns of Tegucigalpa in
the Amarateca Valley. In this case, the land market was not effective
enough at providing serviced land close to existing infrastructure and
required the construction of independent water and sanitation systems
for each new subdivision. The infrastructure developed in Amarateca is
isolated and stand-alone to serve the resident population and minimal
expansions. Without significant investment it will not provide
incentives for new development. As for the sustainability of the
infrastructure, the Amarateca system will need to overcome a very
serious obstacle. Unlike the projects in Choluteca and El Progreso
where the infrastructure provided to the housing settlements was either
integrated into the larger network and annexed by the service provider
or was supported by a technical assistance institution that permanently
advises the local water board, in Amarateca there is no clear service
provider to assure the sustainability of the system. Because SANAA owns
and operates the water and sanitation system for the capital, the
municipality has not had the need to develop institutional capacity or
institutional arrangements to operate and maintain a water and sewerage
system. The possibility of SANAA assuming responsibility for the system
is not realistic since its institutional mandate is limited to the urban
networks of the city. The alternative of having the municipality manage
the services would first require institutional and organizational
reforms within the local administration. The option of creating another
local provider would also imply significant institutional reform and
development. As a result, the constitution of a local water board is
the most realistic option currently available although significant
obstacles still exist and a great deal of capacity building would be
required. Unlike San Jorge, no NGO has maintained a meaningful presence
in these housing projects to advise and provide technical assistance to
the local water board.
New policy instruments
Two recent legal reforms, the Property Law (2004) and the
Territorial Organization Law (2003), have the potential for providing a
sound and updated legal framework to improve the functioning of the land
markets. In the case of the Property Law, the new framework provides a
watershed opportunity to create a single property registry institution,
modernize the adjudication of property rights, and increase secure
tenure for many titles currently under dispute. The Territorial
Organization Law complements and enhances the regulatory authority of
local governments provided for in the Municipal Law (1990) while at the
same time introducing new coordination mechanisms and requirements for
integrating territorial organization at the national, regional, and
local levels. While the Property Law has the potential to make more
far-reaching and structural changes than the Territorial Organization
Law, the key limiting factor for both will be the implementation and
enforcement capacity of their provisions. A number of exogenous factors
exist that will determine the type of impact each law will have on land
markets. These factors can be separated into two general categories of
“setting up the system” and “making it operational”.
In order
for the provisions of the Property Law to be adequately enacted and
enforced, two key variables must be addressed. First, the central
government must provide an adequate budget for the creation of the new
Instituto de la Propiedad (IP). Unlike other laws that create
new institutions or commissions, this is likely to occur since the IP
will be amalgamating existing property registries and offices[11]
under one single institution causing a net budgetary impact close to
zero. Second, the crucial aspect of instituting the real-based registry
(folio real) is paramount to the modernization of the registry
and the improvement of property rights. The wholesale transition from
one registry system to another that, for the first time, links legal
information to a geo-referenced land cadastre will be a formidable
challenge to undertake. The full impact of the Property Law may depend
on the success of this transition and the effective implementation of
the folio real.
In terms of
making the new property rights system operational, three factors will be
pivotal. First, the law provides for decentralized decision-making by
registrars to resolve a specific set of issues rather than submitting
every problem to the court system as was required under the previous
system. While this measure aims to streamline the process, its success
will depend on the professional capacity of the new cadre of
registrars. Second, for those issues requiring resolution through the
court system, a functioning judicial system must be in place in order to
adequately address these disputes. Finally, an important coordination
effort must exist between the IP and local governments regarding land
cadastre information. Municipalities currently have the most updated
and legitimized information on real estate properties that they use for
assessing and collecting property taxes. The de facto ownership
recorded in the municipal cadastres needs to be compared and merged with
the IP’s cadastres. The mere legislation of this coordination is no
guarantee; a concerted effort needs to be made to link the municipal
cadastre database and the IP’s cadastre.
In contrast to the Property Law, the Territorial Organization
Law does not establish new institutions; rather, it more specifically
defines the legal attributes of municipalities in terms of land use
planning regulations and establishes coordination mechanisms at the
regional and national levels. In terms of the Territorial Organization
Law, its effectiveness also depends on “making it work”. In the best
case scenario, municipalities will continue to exercise their leadership
and decision-making ability in establishing and enforcing land uses
within their jurisdictions, while the National Commission for
Territorial Organization and its representatives at the departmental
level (Departmental Commissions for Territorial Organization) focus on
coordinating policies through the regional hierarchy as necessary.
Inasmuch as the implementation of the Territorial Organization Law does
not contradict or undermine the authority of local governments to make
land use decisions in a decentralized manner, the result will be
positive. However, should the provisions in the Territorial
Organization Law be utilized to undermine local authorities or should
the national and departmental commissions be seen as an appellate body
to resolve issues that are not agreeably resolved at the local level,
then greater confusion in regulating land use will result.
As in other countries, the best way to test the limits of
each law will be through the courts. Unfortunately, for countries such
as Honduras that have a weak judicial system that offers highly unequal
access to its citizens, extra-judicial factors are often brought to bear
in the resolution of legal disagreements. A legitimized and transparent
rule of law is important for land markets in particular, and for an open
economy in general. Even though both of these laws has the potential to
clarify transactions and increase transparency in the land market,
without an efficient, effective, and impartial judicial system to
support their enforcement, little positive advances will be made in
eliminating the barriers that exist within a closed market.
Future roles and
behaviors of key land market actors
As demonstrated with the cases of El Progreso and Choluteca,
local governments are capable of playing a unique role in contributing
to land development for low-income housing. In their most aggressive
posture, evident during post-Mitch reconstruction, local governments can
become deal-makers or partners in the land development process. The
positive impact of municipality-as-partner or deal-maker
notwithstanding, a larger, more strategic role for local governments
should be encouraged. As shown by the three cases, the development of
the larger housing projects produces an immediate impact in fulfilling
sorely needed housing solutions, but also results in a more strategic
impact with regards to shaping urbanization patterns of the city. To
fully and successfully address this longer-term impact, local leaders in
developing countries must begin to view land markets and land
development not only as an exercise to satisfy basic residential needs,
but also in terms of economic development and economic competitiveness.
This paradigm shift has occurred in some places, but needs to be
promoted more effectively in cities which will be absorbing the largest
portion of urban growth over the coming years. Each new land
development project needs to be evaluated for both its immediate social
impacts as well as it long-term impact on the city’s competitiveness.
As part of this goal for local governments to take a more
strategic view of land development and the growth of their cities, they
have an opportunity to promote open information regarding the land
market. A large volume of scattered information exists in Honduras
regarding the market, including zoned land uses, growth plans,
infrastructure specifications and carrying-capacities, risk areas, areas
designated for public use, transportation plans and road network
hierarchy, demographic trends, assessment of property values, etc.
However, because of partial access to information indicative of a
captured economy, these figures have not been collected and analyzed
systematically or used to their full potential. More equitable access
to this type of aggregate market analysis can improve decisions made by
public sector policy-makers as well as private sector consumers and
investors.
Given the accessibility of technology, even small- and
medium-sized cities in developing countries now have the ability to
create, manage, and update large databases of geo-referenced
information. Local governments can also serve as focal points for
coordinating information and projections with other entities such as
infrastructure providers, large public landholders (national government)
and other institutional actors (universities, health and education
centers). The opportunities for local government to meaningfully
contribute to the non-regulatory aspects of the land market are
reflected in the land market monitoring methodologies emerging from the
National Center for Smart Growth Research and Education (Knaap 2004) in
the United States. Land market monitoring, although conceptually
simple, is a complex process to manage. The institutional obstacles
existing in developing countries will require the adaptation of these
models, but this type of permanent system would be preferable to the
approach of taking periodic inventories of supply and demand. In
Honduras, a permanent monitoring system has the potential to succeed if
it is linked to other permanent systems that are already being used,
consciously or not, to manage land. The permanent updating that occurs
with the municipal cadastre system or the type of construction and
subdivision permits being awarded by the municipal public works
department are two examples of on-going efforts that could be enhanced
by a land market monitoring system. The approach of performing analyses
based on static inventories at certain periods in time runs the risk of
becoming a periodic exercise disconnected from the dynamics of on-going
land development. Especially in fast growing urban centers, such as the
medium-sized cities in Honduras, land market analysis needs to be an
integral part of local government activity. In a captured economy with
deficient information systems, a tool such as the land market monitoring
advocated by National Center for Smart Growth Research and Education
would be valuable not only for the local government but also for the
private sector investor as well.
Box
1.
The National
Center for Smart Growth Research and Education, located at the
University of Maryland in College Park, Md., is a non-partisan
center for research and leadership training on Smart Growth and
related land use issues nationally and internationally.
"Land
Market Monitoring" is a phrase that describes the processes that
can be employed by governments to monitor residential and other
land uses within a jurisdiction. Done properly and updated
regularly, a Land Market Monitoring system can improve planning
by shedding light on the impacts of urban growth management
policies, the current and future availability of development
capacity, and assist in balancing residential development near
centers of current or future employment.
In a
Land Market Monitoring program, information on land and housing
markets is regularly collected, stored in a geographic
information system (GIS), and used to generate detailed and
timely data on land and housing prices, developable land
supplies, urban development trends, and other measurable
qualities of urban environments.
Many
jurisdictions have adopted urban growth boundaries or other
regulatory restraints on urban development, but few conduct
build-out analyses, estimate vacant land supplies, or monitor
housing affordability. Such information, and more, could be
readily available if local or regional governments established a
Land Market Monitoring program.
The National
Center for Smart Growth Research and Education is currently
assisting the following state and local governments in applying
LMM approaches to their growth needs:
·
The Metro Council of Minneapolis-St. Paul, Minnesota
·
Portland Metro, Oregon
·
The Sacramento Area Council of Governments, California
·
Orange County, Florida
·
The Maryland Department of Planning
Source:
www.smartgrowth.umd.edu |
Under the
promising new Property Law, private investment in the land market should
increase as confidence in secure land tenure grows. The successful
implementation of this law should produce an increase in land
development activity, especially in large markets such as Tegucigalpa.
As noted above, an important assumption in this scenario is that an
effective judicial system will enforce these provisions. Even with more
secure tenure, an ILD analysis of the land market indicates that the
permitting process being implemented by the Central District and other
public entities is complex and time-consuming. An estimated 1,080 days
is currently required to legally purchase private property, subdivide
and construct, at a cost of US$1,083 (ILD 2001). Without specific
reforms, these bureaucratic impediments will continue to restrict
effective land development in the larger markets.
Low-income
families also have a greater opportunity to participate in the formal
land market because of the regularization activities that are outlined
in the law. This regularization program may realistically become
limited by the state’s capacity to process all claims and its ability to
compensate for takings. A great deal of regularization activity should
be expected in Tegucigalpa and along with it, the conversion of dead
capital to active capital. If De Soto’s hypothesis (2000) is correct,
poor families will be able to use their land holdings to leverage
additional credit and create new opportunities for creating wealth. The
underlying assumption that the banking sector will be sufficiently
diversified and have the management capacity to reach out to this new
market of consumers will be tested and may not hold true. Access to
formal title by informal sector dwellers alone cannot be the sole focus
for expanding the credit market and eventually leveraging formally dead
capital into new sources of wealth. Financial institutions need to have
the capacity to innovate and introduce financial products and systems to
meet the needs of the new consumers, while new formal sector actors will
require additional capacities (e.g., small business development, job
training) in order to succeed in inserting themselves, surviving, and
thriving in the formal economic market. The potential for greater
insertion into formal markets by owners of dead capital exists, but new
economic relationships and systems beyond the regularization of land
titles need to accompany and cultivate this transition.
Conclusions and
Recommendations
Poorly
functioning land markets have wide-reaching consequences. In the
immediate term, they constrain formal markets for land development and
may even force economic actors to rely on alternative mechanisms to
satisfy their needs. Over an extended period of time, inadequately
functioning land markets can cause inefficient and ineffective urban
growth and land-use patterns, forcing many of the poorest economic
actors into high risk areas or into locations where services are costly
to provide. As in the case of Honduras before and after Hurricane
Mitch, the injection of significant quantities of capital during the
reconstruction period helped to temporarily level the playing field on
behalf of low-income city dwellers, but did not necessarily produce any
structural or long-term improvements. In Tegucigalpa, even the generous
levels of aid were not able to overcome certain barriers that existed in
the land market, resulting in the development of housing projects in
areas with little or no relationship to the expansion of the city.
The functioning of land markets, however, is not so much an
independent system as it is a dependent market that reflects other types
of institutional, legal, and economic systems. Because these systems
may not be effective in developing countries, a careful analysis of the
institutional capacity and framework is required to understand the
factors that drive change in these land markets. In order to improve
this context and contribute to the on-going debate that affects many
fast-growing medium-sized cities throughout the developing world, the
following recommendations are offered.
1.
Reconstruction efforts are helpful to satisfy immediate housing needs,
but not as useful for affecting structural constraints. In Honduras, the reconstruction efforts that followed
Hurricane Mitch produced important impacts. In the housing sector
alone, reconstruction was responsible for the largest housing boom of
low-income dwellings in the country’s history. It would be
inappropriate, however, to expect that any reconstruction effort, which,
when not accompanied by deep-rooted reforms, will not have an
appreciable impact in terms of structural constraints to land and
housing markets. Ultimately, the nature of the political reform
process (i.e., long consultative processes and coalition-building), and
the nature of reconstruction programs (i.e., fast-tracked investments)
are incompatible.
2. Local
governments can be valuable partners in the land development process,
but have a more important strategic role to play. When forced to address land and housing shortage, as
happened after Hurricane Mitch, medium-sized municipalities provided
valuable leadership as well as financial contributions. Municipalities,
however, can (and should) play a much more strategic role in the growth
of the city. With this objective in mind, municipalities should
adopt a more integrated and long-term approach to land management that
emphasizes the economic competitiveness of their territory. By
relating land markets more closely with economic benefits, key
management tools and methods for monitoring the performance of the land
market should have a better chance of being implemented.
Permanent systems that help manage land market data need to be
introduced as part of the local government’s daily activities
and could be easily complemented by existing databases and data
collection practices. Increased awareness and capacity-building
must take place among locally elected officials, policy-makers, and
managers.
3. Public
information can help liberate a captured economy.
Important market distortions occur in a captured economy where economic
and political elites manipulate market variables for their own private
gain. As the economic costs associated with captured markets are being
understood so too are counter-balancing measures that promote more
competitive practices in the private sector (Hellman et al 2000).
One important contribution to limiting the captured economy is the
availability of public information and market analyses. For the
land market, local governments are prime candidates for collecting the
wide-ranging variables that impact land market behavior. This
information will not only prove valuable for local policy-makers, but
also with private sector investors as well.
4.
Non-regulatory aspects are determinant factors for land markets in the
developing world.
When land regulations exist, but are unenforced because of weak
institutions, they have little or no limiting effect on land market
behavior. For many countries with similarly weak institutions such
as those found in Honduras, non-regulatory aspects will be determining
forces in the land market. The importance of underdeveloped
financial and judicial systems should not be underestimated. In
order to make a long-standing impact in the way in which land markets
operate, reforms in both the financial and judicial sectors need to be
pursued vigorously.
Glenn
Pearce-Oroz
is currently working for the World Bank in Bangladesh as a Senior Water
and Sanitation Specialist. He previously served as a Senior Urban and
Municipal Development Officer for the U.S. Agency for International
Development (USAID) in Honduras, where he managed decentralization and
urban governance activities in 32 cities throughout the country.
[1]
A deliberate distinction is being
made between urban boundaries and urban growth boundaries (UGB’s).
The former is a perimeter commonly established in Honduras by
municipalities to determine the concentration of urban land
uses. These boundaries, however, tend to be geometrically
identified and exist for long periods of time, but are not
designed or updated, as in the case of UGB’s, to promote smart
growth.
[2]
Collective assets of the banking sector were estimated at US$3
billion in 2002 (IMF 2003).
[3]
According to UNDP (2003) 63% of the national urban population
lives below the poverty line.
[4]
For example, a
typical deed of sale specifies the following, "seller is owner
of a lot located in Aldea Remolino, Municipality of Puerto
Cortés, which has the following measurements and boundaries: to
the north 44 feet and bounded by the property of Mrs. A. Paz; to
the south 44 feet and bounded by the property of Mrs. N. Sánchez;
to the east 29 feet and bounded by the highway to La Lima; and
to the west 23 feet and bounded by the property of Mrs. A. Paz
and Mrs. A. Membreño."
[5]
CELADE (2000) identifies Honduras as one of four countries in
the region with delayed urbanization rates. Consequently, these
countries are now experiencing high levels of urban growth (3.0
to 4.0% annual growth) whereas other countries in the region
with more stable urban populations are experiencing more modest
rates of urbanization (1.0 to 1.9% annual growth).
[6]
In the absence of municipal government leadership, the central
government played a large role in the development of the
reconstruction sites.
[7] Preliminary
estimates indicate that families (with a median household income
of US$133 to US$200 per month) are spending US$ 0.86 per person
per round trip for public transportation to Tegucigalpa. Travel
by public transportation can take up to 45 minutes to arrive at
the city’s outskirts.
[8]
The estimated demand for urban residential land is based on
estimated densities calculated by the Urban Institute (2004) for
Villanueva, the fourteenth largest city in Honduras. Low-income
settlements are estimated to have a density of 158 persons per
hectare, middle-income settlements 83.5 persons per hectare, and
high-income settlements 43 inhabitants per hectare. The demand
for land for public use was estimated using simple ratios of 15%
dedicated to streets and rights-of-way and 20% for community
infrastructure. The estimated proportion of what percentage of
the new population would be low-income, middle-income, and
high-income is based on the UNDP Human Development Report
(2003).
[9]
Significant disagreements have taken place between the projects
(Ciudad Nueva and Colonia San Jorge) and their respective
municipal governments since the end of reconstruction, but these
dynamics are more closely related to the local political process
and local political discourse rather than land market forces.
[10]
Despite its legal mandate, the only sewerage system managed by
SANAA is that of Tegucigalpa. In other cities where SANAA
manages the urban water system, such as El Progreso, the
municipality owns, operates and maintains the sewerage system.
[11]
Six disparate registry entities and one cadastre institution
from both the executive and judicial branches of government.
References
Angel, S. 2002. 2002 Annual Roundtable: Access to Land by the Urban
Poor.
Cambridge,
Mass.: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.
Centro de
Diseño, Arquitectura y Construcción (CEDAC). 1999a. Evaluación del
estado de la reconstrucción de viviendas post-Mitch: Municipio de
Choluteca. Tegucigalpa: United States Agency for International
Development (USAID).
CEDAC. 1999b.
Evaluación del estado de la reconstrucción de viviendas post-Mitch:
Municipio de El Progreso.
Tegucigalpa: USAID.
CEDAC. 2002. Best Practices in Housing Reconstruction: An Analysis of
Case Studies from Post-Mitch Honduras.
Tegucigalpa: CEDAC, Avina Foundation.
Centro
Latinoamericano de Demografía (CELADE). 2000. Crecimiento,
estructura y distribución de la población. Informe conciso. New
York: Naciones Unidas.
Clichevsky,
N. 2000. Informalidad y segregación urbana en América Latina.
CEPAL: Santiago, Chile.
De Soto, H. 2000. The
Mystery of Capital. New York: Basic Books.
Estudios,
Proyectos y Planificación, S.A. (EPYPSA). 2003. Plan de Ordenamiento
Territorial para el Valle de Amarateca: Oportunidades de Desarrollo
desde una Perspectiva Metropolitana. Tegucigalpa: Agencia Española
de Cooperación Internacional.
Fundación
para la Vivienda Social y Rural (FUNDEVI). 2005. Cartera Area Urbana
a Diciembre 2004.
Informe Interno.
Hellman, J.S., G. Jones, and D. Kaufmann. 2000. Seize the State,
Seize the Day: State Capture, Corruption and Influence in Transition.
Washington DC: World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2444.
Knaap, G. 2004. Monitoring Land and Housing Markets: an Essential
Tool for Smart Growth. Washington DC: National Center for Housing
and the Environment.
Instituto Libertad y Democracia (ILD) and Consejo Hondureño de la Empresa
Privada (COHEP).
2001.
Activos Prediales y Empresariales Extralegales en Honduras.
Tegucigalpa: COHEP, USAID.
Instituto
Nacional de Estadística (INE). 1974. Censo Nacional de la Población
y de la Vivienda. Tegucigalpa: INE.
INE.
1988. Censo Nacional de la Población y de la Vivienda.
Tegucigalpa: INE.
INE
2001a. Censo Nacional de la Población y de la Vivienda.
Tegucigalpa: INE.
INE
2001b. Proyecciones de población por departamento y municipio años
2001-2015. Tegucigalpa: INE.
International Monetary Fund. 2003. Financial System Stability
Assessment: Honduras. Internal Report. Washington DC: IMF.
International Organization for Migrations (IOM).
1999.
Comunidades Habitacionales de Asistencia Temporal (CHAT) Program.
Monthly Reports.
IOM. 2001.
Encuesta socio-económica de beneficiarios del Exit Program en
Amarateca.
Working
Paper.
Tegucigalpa:
IOM.
METROPLAN.
2005. Cuadros de Urbanizaciones aprobadas de los Años 2000, 2001,
2002, 2003, y 2004. Informe Interno. Tegucigalpa: Alcaldía
Municipal del Distrito Central.
Pisani,
Marcelo. 1997. Sector vivienda: estudio preliminar, informe nacional
sobre desarrollo humano sostenible.
Working Paper.
Tegucigalpa: International Organization for Migrations.
Planning and Development Collaborative International (PADCO).
1998.
Diagnóstico rápido: el mercado de terrenos y los barrios marginales,
ciudad de Tegucigalpa.
Working Paper.
Washington DC: Inter-American Development Bank.
The Urban Institute.
2003.
Volumen Tres: Antecedentes del Plan de uso de suelo y manejo de
crecimiento, Villanueva Hoy y en el futuro. Tegucigalpa: USAID.
Unidad
de Programas y Proyectos de Vivienda (UPPV). 2001. Levantamiento de
inventario de proyectos de vivienda en todo el país: Informe Ejecutivo.
Tegucigalpa: Secretaría de Obras Públicas, Transporte, y Vivienda (SOPTRAVI).
United
Nations Development Programme. 2003. Informe sobre desarrollo
humano Honduras 2003.
New York: United
Nations.
Return to top |